eBooks Search Include Read Aloud for titles that can be read aloud.


 

 Tutors/Experts 
Available 24/7
 
 
Economics  
Marketing  
Mathematics  
Statistics  
Writing  

Chapter 31 Market Based Government
Externality Intervention

Our Economics Learning Center has information for students, teachers, an professionals.

Free Internet Libraries  
improve grades and careers.

Free Stuff  For Students
is an extensive collection.


I. Introduction
    
A. Government subsidies are an attempt to provide externality benefits within reasonable cost limits.
    B. The need for government subsidies lie somewhere between the "clear" benefit of lowering the externality
         costs of severe
pollution to the questionable economic benefit of "pork barrel" (political patronage) 
         programs often generated by logrolling (trading votes in congress). See
Golden Fleece Award
    C. Often the desire by consumers to receive a surplus is balanced with industry's desire for increased economic rent.
    D.
Unintended consquences of government subsidies

II. Government subsidies use direct controls and taxes affect demand and supply
     1. The Clean Air Act of 1990 limited pollution decreasing supply because of the
         increase in marginal cost
     2.
Affecting demand
          a. Tax credits, tax preferences, and loan programs agriculture. education...
              increase taxpayer demand by the taxpayers' marginal tax rate.
          b. Government supports industries like defense and agriculture with large purchases.
     3. Affecting supply
         a. Supporting industries such as agriculture and education with subsidies (loans, in-
             expensive insurance) increases supply, lowering price and increasing quantity sold. 
         b. Organizations such as the Export-Import Bank of the United States, which supports
              export industries, have similar effects.

 

 

III. Externalities and the marketplace from  Welker's Wikinomics Page    

IV. Subsidizing agriculture markets (both buyers and producers)
      A. Farmers sell in an uncertain market
          1. Demand is very inelastic as people's physical needs are limited and 
              lowering price will not substantially increase quantity sold.
          2. Demand increases slowly for most agricultural products as many are 
              inferior goods for which quantity demanded decreases as income increases.
          3. Supply is very inelastic in the short run as crops will grow only so fast.
          4. Supply is volatile because of the weather.
          5. Technology has caused supply to increase substantially.
          6. Annual supply fluctuations cause the prices farmers receive and
              resulting revenue to fluctuate considerably.

   B. Supply and Demand for agricultural products
       
C. Increased supply causes revenue to drop
    

The Bottom Line aei-ideas.org/2013/09/americans-love-to-complain-about-rising-food-prices-here-are-three-reasons-you-should-stop-whining/

1. Inflation has been low
 food2

    D. Solving the farm problem with price supports using parity pricing.
         1. Prices received by farmers should be kept high enough to allow
             a certain amount of agricultural output to purchase a constant 
             amount of goods and services.
             a. A ratio of prices received for crops to prices paid by farmers
                 to live was created using data from 1910 to 1914 as a base.
             b. 100% parity would mean each dollar earned would have a 
                 constant value, i.e., revenue from a bushel of corn would 
                 always buy a toothbrush.
        2. Methods of achieving parity pricing
             a. Increase demand
                 1) Provide programs for the needy (school lunch program). 
                 2) Direct purchase and storage.
                 3) Encouraging the free international trade of agricultural
                      products.
             b. Regulate supply with soil conservation programs.
             c. Decrease risk with subsidized crop insurance and inexpensive
                 loan programs.

        3. Historically prices paid by farmers have increased more rapidly than
           prices received. 
           a. This caused a decline of the family farm and the industrialization 
               of agriculture. 
           b. These changes have complicated questions concerning agricultural
               policy.
   
E. Price supports are basically a price floor resulting in higher prices and 
         a surplus of production.
    F. The question of consumer surplus and economic rent need to be addressed.
        1. In 1991 federal appropriations for agriculture were $52 billion, of which
            more than $30 billion were subsidies designed to keep farm prices high.
        2. Government activity to help farmers adds approximately $400 annually
            to the cost of food purchased by the average American family of four.
   G.
Teacher's Corner: Paying for Farm Subsidies: Library of Economics ...

 

 

 

 

 

2. US spends the least on food
  Share of Spending on Food, 2012 Spending on Food, Per Person Consumer Spending per Person

1. U.S.
 
6.6% $2,273 $34,541
2. Singapore 7.3% $1,422 $19,398
3. U.K. 9.1% $2,214 $24,260
4. Canada 9.6% $2,679 $27,761
5. Austria 10.1% $2,617 $25,908
6. Ireland 10.1% $2,037 $20,093
7. Australia 10.2% $3,814 $37,492
8. Germany 10.9% $2,481 $22,762
9.Switzerland 11.0% $4,943 $44,899
10. Denmark 11.1% $3,036 $27,306
 

3. We spend less and less on food

food1

IV. For more read
     A.
Sports Pork
     B. Wikipedia on subsidies

from /the-senate-is-voting-on-a-955-billion-farm-bill-heres-whats-in-it/\

By Brad Plumer, Washington Post, 610/13

senate farm bill

Free Book Summaries- 3 New York Times Bestsellers1 FREE Audiobook RISK-FREE from Audible

 
This article needs additional references or sources for verification.
Please help improve this article by adding reliable references. (help, get involved!)
Unverifiable material may be challenged and removed.
This article has been tagged since February 2007.

Overview on Subsidies

In standard supply and demand curve diagrams, a subsidy will shift either the demand curve up or the supply curve down. A subsidy that increases production will result in a lower price while a subsidy that increases demand will tend to result in an increase in price. Both cases result in a new Economic equilibrium. Therefore it is essential to consider elasticity when estimating the total costs of a planned subsidy: it equals the subsidy per unit (difference between market price and subsidized price) times the new equilibrium quantity. One category of goods suffers less from this effect: Public goods are — once created — in ample supply and the total costs of subsidies remain constant regardless of the number of consumers; depending on the form of the subsidy, however, the number of producers demanding their share of benefits may still rise and drive costs up.

The recipient of the subsidy may need to be distinguished from the beneficiary of the subsidy, and this analysis will depend on elasticity of supply and demand as well as other factors. For example, a subsidy for consumption of milk by consumers may appear to benefit consumers (or some subset of consumers, such as low-income households); but if supply of milk is constrained and results in higher demand and higher prices, the milk producer may benefit and the consumer may derive no net gain, as the higher prices for milk offset the subsidy. The net effect and identification of winners and losers is rarely straightforward, but subsidies generally result in a transfer of wealth from one group to another (or transfer between sub-groups).

Subsidy may also be used to refer to government actions which limit competition or raise the prices at which producers could sell their products, for example, by means of tariff protection. Although economics generally holds that subsidies may distort the market and produce inefficiencies, there are a number of recognized cases where subsidies may be the most efficient solution.

In many instances, economics may (somewhat counter-intuitively) suggest that direct subsidies are preferable to other forms of support, such as hidden subsidies or trade barriers; although subsidies may be inefficient, they are often less inefficient than other policy tools used to benefit certain groups. Direct subsidies may also be more transparent, which may allow the political process more opportunity to eliminate wasteful hidden subsidies. This problem - that hidden subsidies are more inefficient, but often favored precisely because they are non-transparent - is central to the political-economy of subsidies.

Examples of industries or sectors where subsidies are often found include utilities, gasoline in the United States, welfare, farm subsidies, and (in some countries) certain aspects of student loans.

Types of subsidies

There are many different ways to classify subsidies, such as the reason behind them, the recipients of the subsidy, the source of the funds (government, consumer, general tax revenues, etc). In economics, one of the primary ways to classify subsidies is the means of distributing the subsidy.

In economics, the term subsidy may or may not have a negative connotation: that is, the use of the term may not be prescriptive but descriptive. In economics, a subsidy may nonetheless be characterized as inefficient relative to no subsidies; inefficient relative to other means of producing the same results; "second-best", implying an inefficient but feasible solution (contrasted with an efficient but not feasible ideal), among other possible terminology. In other cases, a subsidy may be an efficient means of correcting a market failure.

For example, economic analysis may suggest that direct subsidies (cash benefits) would be more efficient than indirect subsidies (such as trade barriers); this does not necessarily imply that direct subsidies are good, but that they may be more efficient or effective than other mechanisms to achieve the same (or better) results.

Insofar as they are inefficient, however, subsidies would generally be considered by economists to be bad, as economics is the study of efficient use of limited resources. Ultimately, however, the choice to enact a subsidy is a political choice. Note that subsidies are linked to the concept of economic transfers from one group to another.

Economics has also explicitly identified a number of areas where subsidies are entirely justified by economics, particularly in the area of provision of public goods.

Direct subsidies

Direct subsidies are the most simple, and arguably the least frequently used[citation needed]. They involve a direct cash transfer to the recipient, for example an unemployed person or an agricultural corporation.

Indirect Subsidies

Indirect subsidy is a term sufficiently broad that it may cover most other forms of subsidy. The term would cover any form of subsidy that does not involve a direct transfer.

Labor subsidies

A labor subsidy is any form of subsidy where the recipients receive subsidies to pay for labor costs. Examples may include labor subsidies and tax deductions for workers in industries, such as the film and television industries. (see: Runaway production)

Tax Subsidy

A tax subsidy is any form of subsidy where the recipients receive the benefit through the tax system, usually through the income tax, profit tax, or consumption tax systems. Examples may include tax deductions for workers in certain industries, accelerated depreciation for certain industries or types of equipment, or exemption from consumption tax (sales tax or value added tax).

Production subsidies

In certain cases (to encourage the development of a particular industry, for example), governments may provide direct production subsidies - cash payments for production of a given good or service. Frequently, production subsidies are less easily identifiable, such as minimum price policies. Indirect production subsidies may be less easy to identify, such as infrastructure subsidies.

Regulatory advantages

Policy may directly or indirectly favor one industry, company, product, or class of producer over another by means of regulations. For example, a requirement that full-time government inspectors (at company expense) be present to inspect meat may favor large producers; conversely, if small producers were not required to undergo meat inspections at all, this may constitute a subsidy to that class of producer. It may not be evident or clear that there is a subsidy in many cases.

Infrastructure subsidies

Infrastructure subsidies may be used to refer to a form of indirect production subsidy, whereby the provision of infrastructure (at public expense) may effectively be useful for only a limited group of potential users, such as construction of roads at government expense for a single logging company. The implication is that those users or industries benefit disproportionately from the provision of that infrastructure, at the expense of taxpayers.

In some cases, the "subsidy" may refer to favoring one type of production or consumption over another, effectively reducing the competitiveness or retarding the development of potential substitutes. For example, it has been argued that the use of petroleum, and particularly gasoline, has been "subsidized" or favored by U.S. defense policy, reducing the use of alternative energy sources and delaying their commercial development.

Trade protection (Import)

Measures used to limit imports from other countries may constitute another form of hidden subsidy. The economic argument is that consumers of a given product are forced to pay higher prices for a given good than they would pay without the trade barrier; the protected industry has effectively received a subsidy. Such measures include import quotas, import tariffs, import bans, and others.

Export subsidies (trade promotion)

Various tax or other measures may be used to promote exports that constitute subsidies to the industries favored. In other cases, tax measures may be used to ensure that exports are treated "fairly" under the tax system. The determination of what constitutes a subsidy (or the size of that subsidy) may be complex. In many cases, export subsidies are justified as a means of compensating for the subsidies or protections provided by a foreign state to its own producers

Procurement subsidies

Governments everywhere are relatively large consumers of various goods and services. Subsidies may occur in this process by choice of the products consumed, the producer, the nature of the product itself, and by other means, including payment of higher-than-market prices for goods purchased.

Consumption subsidies

Governments everywhere provide consumption subsidies in a number of ways: by actually giving away a good or service, providing use of government assets, property, or services at lower than the cost of provision, or by providing economic incentives (cash subsidies) to purchase or use such goods. In most countries, consumption of education, health care, and infrastructure (such as roads) are heavily subsidized, and in many cases provided free of charge. In other cases, governments literally purchase or produce a good (such as bread, wheat, gasoline, or electricity) at higher prices than the cost of sale to the public (which may require rationing to control the cost).

The provision of true public goods through consumption subsidies is an example of a type of subsidy that economics may recognize as efficient. In other cases, such subsidies may be reasonable second-best solutions; for example, while it may be theoretically efficient to charge for all use of public roads, in practice, the cost of implementing a system to charge for such use may be unworkable or unjustified.

In other cases, consumption subsidies may be targeted at a specific group of users, such as large utilities, residential home-owners, and others.

 

Tax breaks and corporate welfare

Main article: Corporate welfare

As previously stated, a common form of subsidy is via a tax break. This is a reduction in the normal rate of a particular class of taxes targeted towards an individual or group of companies. Often this is described as "corporate welfare", although that term is also used as a blanket term for all other forms of subsidies. Larger companies who are planning to open a new factory, for example, shop around for a location which will provide them with the biggest tax breaks in a process called a race to the bottom. Locations provide these tax breaks because they often feel that the benefits of job creation will more than offset the decline in tax revenues. Governments of all levels may do this to encourage employment in under-developed areas. Subsidies are given as protection to smaller producers to help them compete with larger companies, to help correct international trade imbalances, to aid industry deemed critical to national security, and to help industry compete with other countries - due to subsidies being common practice throughout the world.

To some, another way that the government subsidizes industry is by failing to regulate externalities. For example, when a company pollutes, it generates savings for itself at public expense, in the form of environmental degradation and public health costs. Thus a cost of production is absorbed by the public. Some individuals argue that this is a form of subsidy of producers (since producers are not paying the full social cost of production). Even where such externalities exist, it is unclear what the most effective way of compensating for the problem is: traditional economic theory suggests that "internalizing" the costs (to the extent possible) is most efficient. It is unclear, however, whether not compensating for externalities (by internalizing costs, regulations, Pigouvian taxes or other means) amounts to a subsidy.

[edit] Subsidies due to the effect of debt guarantees

Another form of subsidy is due to the practice of a government guaranteeing a lender payment if a particular borrower defaults. This occurs in the United States, for example, in certain airline industry loans, in most student loans, in small business administration loans, in Ginnie Mae mortgage backed bonds, and is alleged to occur in the mortgage backed bonds issued through Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. A government guarantee of payment lowers the risk of the loan for a lender, and since interest rates are primarily based on risk, the interest rate for the borrower lowers as well.

[edit] Controversy

One of the most controversial classes of subsidies, especially according to publications such as The Economist, are subsidies benefitting farmers in first-world countries. Charity institutions like Oxfam describe such subsidies as dumping millions of surplus commodities (like sugar) on world markets, destroying opportunities for farmers in developing and poor countries, especially in Africa. For example, the EU is currently spending €3.30 in subsidies to export sugar worth €1 Source: Oxfam briefing paper. These subsidies have remained in place even though many international accords have reduced other forms of subsidies or tariffs.

A view, held by Austrian economists and other free-marketers, is that subsidies do, in general, more harm than good by distorting economic signals.

Sometimes people believe profitable companies to be 'bullying' governments for subsidies and rescue packages, an example of rent-seeking behaviour. For example, [citation needed] in the case with Australian rail operator Pacific National, the company threatened the Tasmanian Government with a pull-out of rail services unless a subsidization was made.

Historical meaning

In the 15s the subsidy was a tax invented in England by Thomas Wolsey in 1513 that taxed based on the ability to pay. It was created in order that Henry VIII could pay for war with France while maintaining his lifestyle.

Compare

See also 

External links

This includes a minimum of $14.7 billion in government subsidies that has gone to the four major league sports —Major League Baseball, the National Football ...
 
Last Chapter  Next Chapter 

Please Visit Our Sponsors

Free Internet Libraries improve grades and careers.

Free Business Book Summaries 3 New York Times Bestsellers

Enjoy the NYT on your Kindle

Chapter 31 Class Discussion Questions Table of Contents
Chapter 31 Homework Questions Economics Free Stuff